THE POLITICS OF SELLING RICE
THE POLITICS OF SELLING RICE
When President
Ferdinand “Bongbong” Marcos Jr. (PBBM) made the bold promise to bring down the
price of rice to ₱20 per kilo, many Filipinos saw it as an ambitious yet
hopeful campaign pledge. As both President and concurrent Secretary of
Agriculture at the time, it was assumed that he had a well-studied strategy
rooted in systemic reforms—perhaps one that addressed the inefficiencies in
rice production, post-harvest losses, and middleman-dominated supply chains.
The public expected a comprehensive, long-term agricultural development plan
that would empower farmers while ultimately lowering consumer prices.
Unfortunately,
what has materialized thus far appears to be a short-term, politically convenient
solution: subsidizing rice to sell it at lower retail prices despite high
production and procurement costs. It seems that the government, through
agencies such as the National Food Authority (NFA), buys rice at a relatively
high wholesale price and sells it at a loss to achieve the promised price
point. This approach may temporarily win public approval and provide relief to struggling
consumers, but it is far from a sustainable economic policy.
Subsidies in
agriculture are not inherently bad. Many countries support their farmers to
protect food security and rural livelihoods. However, subsidies must be smartly
targeted and time-bound, paired with structural reforms such as improving
irrigation systems, providing access to affordable credit and quality seeds,
investing in farm mechanization, and reducing logistics and post-harvest costs.
Without these parallel reforms, subsidies become a band-aid
solution—unsustainable in the long run and potentially harmful to the market.
What is
troubling is that this subsidy-driven approach appears more political than
economic. It creates the illusion of affordability while hiding the actual
costs borne by the government and, ultimately, taxpayers. Worse, it could
distort the rice market. Private traders might avoid competing with
government-subsidized prices, leading to reduced investment in rice trading and
distribution. Local farmers may also suffer if they are forced to sell palay
(un-milled rice) at lower prices due to government-controlled market
expectations, especially when input costs remain high.
Moreover, the
continued reliance on rice importation—used to fill supply gaps and stabilize
prices—hurts domestic producers. Instead of building rice self-sufficiency, the
country becomes more dependent on global markets, vulnerable to price
fluctuations and supply disruptions.
This situation
highlights the intersection of agriculture and politics. Rice is not just a
staple food in the Philippines—it is a politically sensitive commodity. Any
rise in rice prices can quickly lead to public discontent. This is why
administrations often prioritize short-term populist solutions over long-term
agricultural investment. But these political calculations come at a cost: the
neglect of meaningful agricultural reform, farmer welfare, and national food
security.
In conclusion,
while the intent to provide affordable rice is noble and politically strategic,
the current approach under PBBM lacks sustainability. For the ₱20 rice promise
to become reality—not just a populist slogan—what is needed is bold
agricultural reform, not just subsidies. Only by strengthening local
production, streamlining the supply chain, and empowering farmers can the dream
of affordable, homegrown rice be realized—beyond politics, and for the
long-term benefit of the nation.
Ramon
Ike V. Seneres, www.facebook.com/ike.seneres
iseneres@yahoo.com,
09088877282, senseneres.blogspot.com
06-16-2025
Comments
Post a Comment